The Marijuana Opportunity Reinvestment and Expungement (MORE) Act, introduced July 23, 2019 simultaneously by House Judiciary Committee Chairman Jerold Nadler (D-NY) and U.S. Senator Kamala Harris (D-CA), is a major step toward a just and logical marijuana policy in the United States. A central feature of the legislation is the creation of a Community Investment Grant Program to benefit those communities and individuals who have been hurt by marijuana prohibition.
Specifically, the Community Investment Grant Program would provide "eligible entities with funds to administer services for individuals most adversely impacted by the War on Drugs, including—
(1) job training;
(2) reentry services;
(3) legal aid for civil and criminal cases, including expungement of cannabis convictions;
(4) literacy programs;
(5) youth recreation or mentoring programs; and
(6) health education programs."
This is good stuff, but the grant program is funded by an "Opportunity Trust Fund" that is funded by a tax on all legal cannabis products (except for medical cannabis). The tax is set at 5 percent of the price of the cannabis product is sold.
Taxing is important and hard. Mark Kleiman wrote an excellent analysis of the issues involved in drug taxation in his 1992 treatise, Against Excess, pp. 69-80. Taxes are designed primarily for revenue, but influence behavior. Taxes can reduce unwanted behaviors, but can lead to evasion. If a tax is hard to collect and easily evaded that is counterproductive. Excessively high taxes, such as the infamous 1937 tax of $100 per ounce of marijuana if transferred to a person who was not registered as a physician, etc. was intended as a prohibition. (For comparison, a new Ford sedan cost $850.)
Taxing the price seems stupid to me, completely aside from the question of whether this percentage is the right amount.
First, we have seen that in the states, such as Washington and Colorado, that have first legalized retail sales of marijuana, that the retail price has been steadily dropping. Once this law takes effect, it is likely that the source of funds for the program is going to start shrinking. If we believe that the Community Investment Grant program is a good idea and needs to be funded, relying on a tax that is going to produce less revenue over time is not a good idea. Relying on the price of marijuana that is going to be declining means that the remedial effects of this program will shrink, not grow.
Second, we need to think about the impact of the taxation on behavior, i.e., on the consumption of THC and how high people are getting. As a public health matter, using the tax to reduce the amount of intoxication is a good idea. For the millions of recreational users -- once a week or so -- the amount of the tax will be negligible. But for those who use many times a day, the taxation becomes a more serious way to influence behavior by both depressing use or encouraging entry into treatment if use is problematic. Taxing the volume of THC being sold is the best public health approach.
Of course higher taxes are not "free." A tax that is easily and widely evaded is a problem, and collection can be challenging. If there is wide disparity in the state tax rates on cannabis products, interstate smuggling of cannabis will become like the interstate smuggling of low-taxed cigarettes.
Thus, third, the tax should be imposed at the point of production, not at the retail level, where evasion is easy.
There is extensive evasion of high state and city taxes. In
Chicago, according to a 2010 paper, as much as 3/4 of the cigarettes consumed in Chicago were obtained outside the city to avoid paying a $2.68 per pack tax.
In New York City, the current combined city and state tax on a package of 20
cigarettes is $5.85. Last year, the Mackinac Center for Public Policy estimated that 56% of the cigarettes consumed in New York State were smuggled and the state lost $1.5 billion in tax revenue.
And, as we saw with Eric Garner, who was killed by New York police officer Daniel Pantaleo on the suspicion of selling "loosies" (single, untaxed cigarettes), the enforcement of these taxes can range from erratic to catastrophic.
Taxing at the retail level is counterproductive and potentially dangerous.
Wednesday, July 24, 2019
Marijuana Opportunity Reinvestment and Expungement (MORE) Act won't deliver
Sunday, June 13, 2010
Tax benefits of legalizing marijuana -- a history lesson?
Daniel Okrent, the author of Last Call, a new book on alcohol Prohibition, writes in the Week in Review in The New York Times, on June 13, 2010, about the 1920s arguments of business leaders to repeal Prohibition in order to tax alcohol in order to end the relatively new income tax.
Okrent's history is fascinating, but his reporting is seriously flawed. He lazily lays out a specious claim and then attacks supporters of the Tax and Regulate initiative as "indulging a fantasy of income tax relief emerging from a cloud of legalized marijuana smoke." Okrent does not identify anyone in California, or any supporter of the initiative, for making the kinds of extreme claim made on March 19, 1928 by Pierre S. DuPont about ending alcohol prohibition, "the revenue of the government would be increased sufficiently to warrant the abolition of the income tax and corporation tax." But Okrent acknowledged that in the first year of the repeal of alcohol prohibition, the federal taxation alone amounted to nine percent of total federal revenue!
He says some (anonymous) persons "even believe that a tax on marijuana, which could be legalized by California voters this November, could lead to a reduction in the state's income tax." What is so surprising about this shoddy piece is the Okrent served for three years as the Public Editor of The New York Times, charged with upholding the highest standards of journalism at The Times by flagging the failings of Times writers. One of those standards is to attribute ideas and claims. His current counterpart at The Washington Post, Ombudsman Andrew Alexander, for example, writes today in his column about this particular sin of journalism, anonymity.
It is with specious suggestion that the California Tax, Control and Regulate Initiative is attacked.
Of course the question of tax savings is raised, and it is an important issue with a wide range of estimates.
In the New York Times Freakonomics blog in May 2009, Harvard professor Jeffrey Miron suggests nationwide marijuana legalization revenues of about $7 billion if it were taxed at rates similar to those of alcohol or tobacco.
Paul Armentano, in that blog, cites Dr. Jon Gettman's estimate of $31 billion in revenues, and a California revenue agency's estimate of $1.3 billion annually.
No one who knows the size of government today is going to claim that the tax on marijuana is going to enable the abolition of the income tax. Okrent's column is the crudest journalistic sleight of hand.